Economic Concepts: Efficiency, Market Failure, Property Rights, and more ECX5001 Monash University Session 1 What is environmental economics? Application of standard economic tools to specific types of goods • Goods with externalities • Public goods What questions can we address with enviro. econ.? Plastics pollution as an example: 1. Why is it happening (behaviorally)? ▶ Individuals don’t have an incentive to drastically cut back 2. Why is it hard to solve? ▶ Plastics pollution is global and abatement is a public good 3. What are the benefits of mitigation? ▶ There are many, some of which are hard to measure 4. What are the costs of mitigation? ▶ Never forget opportunity cost! 5. How to optimally manage plastics? ▶ Find optimal quantity of plastic use ▶ Market-based solutions can minimize cost of mitigation 6. How to appropriately weigh costs and benefits? ▶ Not straightforward since many benefits accrue in the future Economic efficiency Economic efficiency ∼ maximize net benefits (i.e. economic surplus). • An allocation of resources is efficient if it maximizes the overall economic surplus (i.e. sum of consumer and producer surpluses). • As we shall see shortly, efficiency is achieved by equating marginal benefits and marginal costs → “equimarginal principle”. • Technically, we are discussing “static efficiency” right now, where time is not a factor. Note: We will sometimes use “efficient” and “socially optimal” interchangeably. Consumer surplus graph Consumer surplus ∼ difference between what consumers are willing to pay for a good and what they actually pay. D Q* P* S Each point on the demand curve represents willingness to pay Price Quantity Consumer surplus Producer surplus graph Producer surplus ∼ difference between what producers are willing to accept for a good and what they actually receive. Quantity P* Q* D S Price Each point on the supply curve represents the cost of production Producer surplus Market equilibrium graph • Total economic surplus is defined as the consumer surplus plus the producer surplus. • In a competitive equilibrium (D = S), total surplus is maximized P* Q* Price Quantity CS PS Total surplus = CS + PS S=MC D=MB The “equimarginal principle” Equimarginal principle ∼ The efficient level of an economic activity X ∗ occurs where marginal benefit equals marginal cost, i.e. MB(X ∗) = MC (X ∗). • Recall that Supply/Demand is another way of talking about MC and MB ▶ Demand curve is defined by consumers’ marginal benefits (D = MB). ▶ Supply curve is defined by producers’ marginal costs (S = MC ) • In Enviro. Econ., we often talk about MC and MB without explicitly talking about the production of goods (i.e., Supply/Demand) ▶ E.g. The efficient level of pollution control is where the incremental benefit of the last unit of abatement equals its incremental cost. “equimarginal principle” for pollution abatement: total vs. marginal graphs Total L Marginal x $ $/Unit Cost (X) Benefit (X) Abatement (X) Abatement (X) Max net benefits MB(X) Slopes parallel at MB=MC MC(X) Defining property rights Property rights ∼ Entitlements defining the owner’s rights, privileges, and limitations for use of a resource. Property rights are given primacy in environmental economics. • Well-defined rights are necessary for an efficient societal outcomes within market-based economies. • Characteristics of an efficient property rights structure: 1. Exclusivity — All the benefits and costs should only accrue to the owner. 2. Transferability — Property rights should be transferable to others. 3. Enforceability — Property rights should be secure from seizure or encroachment. Market Failure & Externalities Market failure Market failure ∼ Inefficient social outcomes due misaligned private interests or misallocation of resources. • The “invisible hand” does not maximize social net benefit via decentralized decisions. In environmental economics, market failure often arises because “exclusivity” of property rights is violated. E.g.,: • Externalities • Public goods/bads Externalities Externality ∼ A cost or benefit, not transmitted through prices, caused by someone else’s actions. • “An externality results when the actions of one individual (or firm) have a direct, unintentional, and uncompensated effect on the well-being of other individuals or the profits of other firms.” — K&O Externalities reflect the (in)completeness of markets. • Decision makers do not fully internalize costs and benefits. • Property rights are not well-defined. Negative externalities Negative externalities impose a cost on a third party. • Pollution from a factory, fisheries bycatch, second-hand cigarette smoke, crying baby on an airplane, etc. Marginal social costs (all costs to society) will not equal marginal private costs (producer’s costs). • Induces deadweight loss through this difference (i.e. the marginal external cost). • Deadweight loss is simply a loss in social surplus −→ figure on next slide. Bottom line: The market will produce too much of a good (at too low cost) in the presence of a negative externality. Negative externalities basic graph • PMC: Private Marginal Cost (a.k.a Supply or Marginal Cost) • MEC: Marginal Externality Cost • SMC: Social Marginal Cost (PMC + MEC) • DWL: Deadweight Loss Price Quantity D=MB Qm Pm Q* P* MEC S=PMC SMC DWL Negative externalities (numerical example) Let’s try a practice example: A market for steel. • Demand is defined by the marginal benefits curve: PD = 18− Q. • Supply is defined by the (private) marginal costs curve: PM = Q. • But there are external costs from steel production. The marginal external costs are increasing with production; each unit produced increases the MEC by $1 (i.e., MEC = Q). ▶ Sketch the market supply and demand for steel. ▶ How much steel will the market produce? ▶ Draw the social supply curve. ▶ What is the socially optimal amount of steel? ▶ What is the deadweight loss associated with the market equilibrium? Negative externalities: numerical example graph Market Equilibrium SMC P 18 Q Ps Q 18 sepmc 18 Q Q 18 20 12 Qu 9 9 Lowe Social OptimumPs DMC Q MEC Q SMC PMCTSMC 6 9 18 SME 20 DWI 18 0 20 18 39SMC Q91 18 9 6 TWC I 97 37 13.5 Positive externalities Postive externalities confer a benefit on a third party. • Vaccinations and flu jabs, R&D spillovers, neighbourhood effects, etc. The reciprocal of the negative externality case that we’ve just seen. Bottom line: The market will produce too little of a good (at too high cost) in the presence of a positive externality. Public Goods A taxonomy of regimes Nonrivalry ∼ My consumption of a good does not diminish the amount available for others. Nonexcludability ∼ Cannot exclude others from enjoying the benefits of a good once it is provided (even if they don’t pay for it). A Taxonomy of regimes (cont.) Nonrivalry N on ex cl u d ab ili ty PURE PRIVATE GOODS OPEN-ACCESS RESOURCES CLUB GOODS PURE PUBLIC GOODS Open-access leads to tragedy of the commons Open-access resources are non-excludable and rival. E.g., • Fisheries • Aquifers • Oil reserves Open-access leads to “tragedy of the commons” Public goods Public goods are both nonrival and nonexcludable. • E.g. Biological diversity −→ Amount of genetic variation among individuals within a single species and the number of species in a community (ecosystem). • Other examples include charming landscape, clean air, etc. • Individuals have an incentive to “free ride” −→ derive benefit from public goods without contributing to the supply of the good. Bottom line: Public goods are underprovided by the market because of the free-rider problem. Socially Optimal Allocation of Public goods vs. private goods In a standard Supply/Demand setup, efficient allocation determined by how you aggregate individual demand curves. • Private goods: Aggregate horizontally because each unit can only be consumed by 1 individual ▶ For a particular price, how many units demanded? • Public goods: Aggregate vertically because each unit can be consumed by everyone ▶ For a particular quantity, what is society’s WTP? Public vs private goods graph 4 4 MC L I 2 4 95 1 6 5 Me 2 4 Market demand (private good)Individual demands Market demand (public good) Public goods graph takeaways • Vertical summation of demands tells us socially optimal quantity for public goods. • How much is provided in market equilibrium (P=2)? ▶ Suppose the blue line is A and green is B ▶ At P = 2, note that B’s quantity demanded is zero. ▶ A demands 1 unit, and since nobody else in the market demands any at P = 2, they will buy it. ▶ 1 unit is provided (by A), and B gets to free-ride! This unique situation occurs because only one market participant demands the good at P = 2. • How much is provided in market equilibrium (P=0.5)? ▶ Both A and B demand a positive quantity ▶ Because both get to consume the good if the other buys it, both have the incentive to fee-ride off the other. ▶ Private allocation graph doesn’t tell us market allocation ▶ Need game theory to determine best responses Model of public goods: model preliminaries N identical individuals w : income x : amount of private good G : amount of public good Px = PG = 1 Utility = U(x ,G ) g : individual’s contribution G¯ others’ contribution → G = G¯ + g w = g + x • Budget constraint; if we contribute to G , it reduces money available for x → Utility = U(w − g , G¯ + g) Model of public goods: graph intuition (1) • Consider tradeoff between my contribution (g) and others’ contribution G¯ . See below for graph. • Remember, as g ↑, G ↑ (U ↑), x ↓ (U ↓) • Remember, an indifference curve shows all combinations of G¯ and g to which I am indifferent - starting at G¯1 (and g = 0), what could the indifference curve look like? ▶ Straight up? My contribution is constant at 0 and others’ contribution increases. I’d be on a higher indifference curve. (impossible) ▶ Horizontal? Increased utility from G exactly offset by decreased utility from x (possible, but assume no) ▶ Upward sloping? G must increase by more than my contribution g to offset my lost utility from x (possible, but assume no) ▶ Downward sloping? I value G more than x , in fact so much more that my utility will remain constant even if others contribute slightly less G¯ (yes!). Because G¯1 is so low (and thus I have little G and a lot of x), the MRS between G and x favours more G . Model of public goods: graph intuition (2) • At higher initial G¯ like the initial MRS between G and x is relatively more favorable toward x (because you already have so much G). • At high enough initial (G¯4), indifference curve never slopes down • Consider a fixed level of G¯ , how would you choose g? ▶ Choose g such that you’re on the highest possible indifference curve (i.e., at the minimum on the curve). ▶ At G¯0, choose g0. ▶ Eventually (at G¯4), it is optimal to contribute nothing (g = 0). ▶ The line between each of these points is the “best response” line • Because consumers are identical, we know G¯ = (n − 1)g ▶ Defines a basic relationship between G¯ and g • Market equilibrium: where “best response” line crosses G¯ = (n − 1)g • Efficient allocation: highest indifference curve touching G¯ = (n − 1)g Model of public goods graph O Model of public goods graph U Model of public goods graph G Because everyones know G ngand G m Basicrelationship between Gandg Slope n I Model of public goods graph MarketAllocation 9m EfficientAllocation g g gm Public bads The reciprocal of public goods. • E.g. Plastic pollution. ▶ I buy things in plastic packaging. ▶ The marginal benefit that I would see from my decrease in plastics use is negligible. But the cost of changing my behaviour is high. ▶ Requires policies that change incentives at every level −→ we’ll revisit this issue later in the course. Bottom line: Public bads are overprovided by the market because of the free-rider problem. Pursuit of Efficiency The pursuit of efficiency We’ve already shown: • Goods with negative externalities are over-provided relative to the social optimum (vice-versa for goods with positive externalities) • Public goods are under-provided relative to the social optimum (vice-versa for public bads) Next: • How do we get from the market equilibrium to the social optimum? The Coase Theorem Ronald Coase’s (1960) insight: We don’t need government to solve our problems as long as we are able to negotiate freely with each other. Coase Theorem ∼ Absent transaction costs, private bargaining will result in an efficient resolution of negative externalities (without government intervention), as long as property rights are fully allocated to at least one party. What makes this result so striking is that it holds irrespective of who holds the initial property right(s). • Only the distribution of costs and benefits among the effective parties is changed. Coasean bargaining example Consider two parties: steel plant and riverside resort hotel • Steel plant pollutes the river, which flows near the resort hotel ▶ Steel production has a negative externality (affecting hotel) Coasean bargaining graph Smc PMC C D Price A B Q Qm Coasean bargaining graph Suppose steel producer has right to pollute • PS: A+B+C • TEC: B+C+D • Difference in PS between Qm and Q∗: C • Difference in TEC between Qm and Q∗: C+D ▶ Equal to hotel’s maximum WTP to reduce production from Qm to Q ∗ Would steel plant accept payment of C+1,...,C+D to reduce production to Q∗? • With free bargaining (zero transaction costs), equilibrium steel production is Q∗. Coasean bargaining graph Suppose hotel has right to clean water • Difference in PS between 0 and Q∗: A+B • Difference in TEC between 0 and Q∗: B ▶ Equal to steel plants’s minimum WTA to increase production from 0 to Q∗ Would hotel accept payment of B+1,...,B+A to increase production to Q∗? • With free bargaining (zero transaction costs), equilibrium steel production is Q∗. The Coase Theorem (cont.) Advantages of Coasean Solution (i.e. just assign property rights): • Solution is efficient when conditions are right. • Government doesn’t need to guess/estimate private marginal damages and benefits (information asymmetries). Disadvantages of Coase: • Bargaining breaks down with transactions costs. • Fails when n > 2 (Ellingsen and Paltseva, REStud 2016). • Suffers from free-riding when goods are non-excludable. • Can lead to distorted incentives −→ pollute simply to extract payment (ransom?) from others. What’s next In future weeks, we focus on government intervention: • Limiting production to some optimal Q∗. • Pollution taxes, emissions trading schemes, zoning laws, technology requirements, etc.
学霸联盟